Prospect theory: A parametric analysis of functional forms in Brazil

Main Article Content

Robert Eugene Lobel
Marcelo Cabus Klotzle
Paulo Vitor Jordão da Gama Silva
Antonio Carlos Figueiredo Pinto

Abstract

This study aims to analyze risk preferences in Brazil based on prospect theory by estimating the risk aversion parameter of the expected utility theory (EUT) for a select sample, in addition to the value and probability function parameter, assuming various functional forms, and a newly proposed value function, the modified log. This is the first such study in Brazil, and the parameter results are slightly different from studies in other countries, indicating that subjects are more risk averse and exhibit a smaller loss aversion. Probability distortion is the only common factor. As expected, the study finds that behavioral models are superior to EUT, and models based on prospect theory, the TK and Prelec weighting function, and the value power function show superior performance to others.  Finally, the modified log function proposed in the study fits the data well, and can thus be used for future studies in Brazil. 

Downloads

Download data is not yet available.

Metrics

Metrics Loading ...

Article Details

How to Cite
LOBEL, R. E.; KLOTZLE, M. C.; SILVA, P. V. J. da G.; PINTO, A. C. F. Prospect theory: A parametric analysis of functional forms in Brazil. RAE - Revista de Administracao de Empresas , [S. l.], v. 57, n. 5, p. 495–509, 2017. DOI: 10.1590/S0034-759020170507. Disponível em: https://periodicos.fgv.br/rae/article/view/71818. Acesso em: 24 may. 2024.
Section
Articles

References

Abdellaoui, M. (2000). Parameter-free elicitation of utility and probability weighting functions. Management Science, 46(11), 1497- 1512.

Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H., & L’Haridon, O. (2008). A tractable method to measure utility and loss aversion under prospect theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36(3), 245-266. doi:10.1007/s11166- 008-9039-8

Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H., & L’Haridon, O. (2013). Sign-dependence in intertemporal choice. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 47(3), 225- 253. doi:10.1007/s11166-013-9181-9

Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H., & Paraschiv, C. (2007). Loss aversion under prospect theory: A parameter-free measurement. Management Science, 53(10), 1659-1674.

Abdellaoui, M., Vossmann, F., & Weber, M. (2005). Choice-based elicitation and decomposition of decision weights for gains and losses under uncertainty. Management Science, 51(9), 1384-1399.

Allais, M. (1953). Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulats et axiomes de l’ecole americaine. Econometrica, 21(4), 503-546. doi:10.2307/1907921

Attema, A. E., Brouwer, W. B. F., & L’Haridon, O. (2013). Prospect theory in the health domain: A quantitative assessment. Journal of Health Economics, 32(6), 1057-1065. doi:10.1016/j.jhealeco.2013.08.006

Barberis, N., & Huang, M. (2008). Stocks as lotteries: The implications of probability weighting for security prices. American Economic Review, 98(5), 2066-2100.

Barberis, N., Huang, M., & Santos, T. (2001). Prospect theory and asset prices. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 1-53. doi:10.1162/003355301556310

Bernoulli, D. (1954). Exposition of a new theory on the measurement of risk. Econometrica, 22(1), 23-36. doi:10.2307/1909829

Booij, A., van Praag, B., & van de Kuilen, G. (2010). A parametric analysis of prospect theory’s functionals for the general population. Theory and Decision, 68(1-2), 115-148. doi:10.1007/s11238-009-9144-4

Bui, T. (2009). Prospect Theory and Functional Choice. A Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate School in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Erasmus Mundus Master: Models and Methods of Quantitative Economics (QEM), Bielefeld University and The University of Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne.

Camerer, C. F., & Ho, T.-H. (1994). Violations of the betweenness axiom and nonlinearity in probability. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8(2), 167-196. doi:10.1007/BF01065371

Ellsberg, D. (1961). Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75(4), 643-669.

Fishburn, P. C., & Kochenberger, G. A. (1979). Two-piece Von NeumannMorgenstern utility functions. Decision Sciences, 10(4), 503-518. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5915.1979.tb00043.x

Gerber, H. U., & Pafum, G. (1998). Utility functions: From risk theory to finance. North American Actuarial Journal, 2(3), 92-94. doi:10.1080/ 10920277.1998.10595731

Goldstein, W. M., & Einhorn, H. J. (1987). Expression theory and the preference reversal phenomena. Psychological Review, 94(2), 236- 254. doi:10.1037/0033-295X.94.2.236

Gomes, F. J. (2005). Portfolio choice and trading volume with loss‐averse investors. The Journal of Business, 78(2), 675-706. doi:10.1086/427643

Gonzalez, R., & Wu, G. (1999). On the shape of the probability weighting function. Cognitive Psychology, 38(1), 129-166. doi:10.1006/ cogp.1998.0710

Harrison, G., & Rutström, E. (2009). Expected utility theory and prospect theory: One wedding and a decent funeral. Experimental Economics, 12(2), 133-158. doi:10.1007/s10683-008-9203-7

Harrison, G. W., Humphrey, S. J., & Verschoor, A. (2010). Choice under uncertainty: Evidence from Ethiopia, India and Uganda. The Economic Journal, 120(543), 80-104. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02303.x

Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644-1655.

Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE). (2014). Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios (Pnad) Contínua. Brasilia, DF.

Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263-292. doi:10.2307/1914185

Karmarkar, U. S. (1978). Subjectively weighted utility: A descriptive extension of the expected utility model. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 21(1), 61-72. doi:10.1016/0030-5073(78)90039-9

Karmarkar, U. S.. (1979). Subjectively weighted utility and the Allais Paradox. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 24(1), 67-72. doi:10.1016/0030-5073(79)90016-3

Köbberling, V., & Wakker, P. P. (2005). An index of loss aversion. Journal of Economic Theory, 122(1), 119-131. doi:10.1016/j.jet.2004.03.009

Liebenehm, S., & Waibel, H. (2014). Simultaneous estimation of risk and time preferences among small-scale cattle farmers in West Africa. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 96(5), 1420-1438. doi:10.1093/ajae/aau056

Liu, E. M. (2012). Time to change what to sow: Risk Preferences and technology adoption decisions of cotton farmers in China. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1386-1403. doi:10.1162/REST_a_00295

Machina, M. J. (2008). Non-expected utility theory. In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. London, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.

Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77- 91. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.x

Nguyen, Q., & Leung, P. (2009). Do Fishermen have Different Attitudes Toward Risk? An Application of Prospect Theory to the Study of Vietnamese Fishermen. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 34(3), 518-538.

Nguyen, Q., & Leung, P. (2010). How nurture can shape preferences: An experimental study on risk preferences of Vietnamese fishers. Environment and Development Economics, 15(5), 609-631. doi:10.1017/S1355770X10000203

Palacios-Huerta, I., & Serrano, R. (2006). Rejecting small gambles under expected utility. Economics Letters, 91(2), 250-259. doi:10.1016/j. econlet.2005.09.017

Prelec, D. (1998). The probability weighting function. Econometrica, 66(3), 497-527. doi:10.2307/2998573

Rieger, M. O., Wang, M., & Hens, T. (2011). Prospect theory around the world (October 31, 2011). NHH Dept. of Finance & Management Science Discussion Paper No. 2011/19.

Rieger, M., & Wang, M. (2008). Prospect theory for continuous distributions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36(1), 83-102. doi:10.1007/s11166-007-9029-2

Rieger, M. O., & Bui, T. (2011). Too risk-averse for prospect theory? Modern Economy, 2(4), 691-670. doi:10.4236/me.2011.24077

Rieger, M. O., Wang, M., & Hens, T. (2017). Estimating cumulative prospect theory parameters from an international survey. Theory and Decision, 82(4), 567-596. doi:10.1007/s11238-016-9582-8

Schmidt, U., & Traub, S. (2002). An experimental test of loss aversion. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 25(3), 233-249. doi:10.1023/A:1020923921649

Scholten, M., & Read, D. (2014). Prospect theory and the “forgotten” fourfold pattern of risk preferences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 48(1), 67-83. doi:10.1007/s11166-014-9183-2

Stott, H. P. (2006). Cumulative prospect theory’s functional menagerie. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 32(2), 101-130. doi:10.1007/s11166-006-8289-6

Tanaka, T., Camerer, C. F., & Nguyen, Q. (2010). Risk and time preferences: Linking experimental and household survey data from Vietnam. American Economic Review, 100(1), 557-571. doi:10.1257/ aer.100.1.557

Tu, Q. (2005). Empirical analysis of time preferences and risk aversion. Tilburg University: CentER, Center for Economic Research.

Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297-323.

Tversky, A., & Wakker, P. (1995). Risk attitudes and decision weights. Econometrica, 63(6), 1255-1280. doi:10.2307/2171769

von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, USA: Princeton University Press.

Wakker, P. P. (2008). Explaining the characteristics of the power (CRRA) utility family. Health Economics, 17(12), 1329-1344. doi:10.1002/hec.1331

Wu, G., & Gonzalez, R. (1996). Curvature of the probability weighting function. Management Science, 42(12), 1676-1690.

Zeisberger, S., Vrecko, D., & Langer, T. (2012). Measuring the time stability of Prospect Theory preferences. Theory and Decision, 72(3), 359-386. doi:10.1007/s11238-010-9234-3